The session is on Radio National, Australia’s effort at highbrow airings on the wireless. And, to be fair, it often does not disappoint. But on this occasion, there was a general sense of bonhomie amongst the participants on the Big Ideas segment, a glee about living in a glorious country far in advance of any on this terminally doomed earth. It sounded, in many ways, like the fond, electoral reiterations of the lately victorious prime minister, Scott Morrison: Australians live in a glorious country of few imperfections, so boo to the rest of you, savages of distant lands.
The theme of the jovial self-congratulation of the panellists, featuring historians Judith Brett and Clare Wright, with jolly ABC moderator Annabel Crabb, was Suffragettes, referenda and sausages: the history of democracy in Australia, recorded at the Sydney Writers Festival on May 2 this year. The smug sense of the topic could be gathered from Radio National’s introduction to the program. “Australia was head of the pack with votes for women, an electoral commission and compulsory voting.”
The fact that Australia, along with New Zealand, was a pioneer in voting systems is undeniable. The secret ballot was born down under, as it were. But what becomes clear in the themes of such panellists, and their publications, is a self-satisfied sense that compulsory voting is the indispensable tool to keep the enthusiastic nutters out and keep the beige and maliciously dull in. The “minority” are not in charge in Australia, goes this claim. Compulsory voting, as Crabb et al would have us believe, does away with the chance Australia might get a Donald Trump, for instance, victorious on the crest of an indignant white wave that flooded the polling booths when it mattered most.
Section 245 of the Commonwealth Electoral Act 1918 is a delightful bit of drafting that brings the policing power of the state to bear upon an elector’s choice. It is condescending, the parent’s rebuke, a grand wrap across the knuckles of the disobedient. Not voting without a “valid and sufficient reason” means a sanction. Not voting often means a very stiff fine indeed. Cognates are to be found in countries such as Brazil, which punishes the non-voter by denying work in the public sector, loans from public banks or obtaining a passport.
Voting is compulsory in 19 of the 166 so-called electoral democracies (numbers on this vary – one puts it at 30), but Australia is only one of nine that enforce it. Its introduction and swift passage via a private member’s bill in 1924 prompted the legal historian Geoffrey Sawer to claim that, “No major departure in the federal political system had ever been made in so casual a fashion.” The converse is true: that compelling individuals to vote, a state directive as it were, was perfectly acceptable and hardly worthy of debate. The legacy of obedience in penal societies runs deep.
As Brett puts it, “People from our sister democracies are often astonished that Australians are compelled to turn up to vote: it seems an affront to freedom. We in reply are appalled at their low turnouts and the election of leaders and governments by a minority of voters.”
What works such as Brett’s insist upon is a certain misplaced legitimacy. To give electors the choice of turning up to the polls is something of an encouragement of illegitimacy. Noses are turned up at voting outcomes where electors had a choice of turning up to their polling booths, yet decided to stay at home. The results are scorned. “Britain’s disastrous 2016 decision to leave the European Union was carried by a slim majority of the 72.2% of voters who turned out.” Writing in elevated tones of disapproval, Brett also notes that the 2016 US presidential election saw a percentage turnout in the high fifties. “Donald Trump did not have the support of the majority of voters, but neither would Hillary Clinton had she won.”
These observations do little in terms of evaluating the notion of informed choice in compulsory voting systems. Many Australian voters are baffled when they do vote about what a bicameral legislature is, or that they have to vote for an upper chamber (the Senate) and the lower House of Representatives. The idea that voters are also “reading the policies,” the favourite brush-off line of a confused voter seduced by false complexities, is the grand icing on the cake of deception. Does an apathetic vote have real value?
When the Electoral Act’s exemption of a “valid and sufficient reason” has been challenged, the results for the abstainer have been meagre. The Australian High Court gave short shrift to the political opinions of a citizen who refused to vote in the 1926 decision of Judd v McKeon. Judd, a socialist, was keen to argue that the candidates were all representatives of the capitalist order and did not need his preference to perpetuate it. Expressing “an objection to the social order of the community in which he lives,” according to Chief Justice Knox and Justices Duffy and Starke, was “not a valid and sufficient reason for refusing to exercise his franchise.”
The case law is resolutely anti-intellectual on the subject. Thoughts, ideas and philosophies matter less than the practical issues of illness, accident or natural events that prevent a person from casting a ballot. The High Court acknowledges, for instance, that a compulsory vote need not be exercised if the “intending voter on his way to the poll was diverted to safe life, or to prevent crime, or to assist at some great disaster.” This lends itself to a firm conclusion: the fact of voting is more significant than its cerebral or spiritual content. Merely having “a subjective incapacity on the part of the voter to determine that he prefers one candidate in an election to another,” opined the Supreme Court of Victoria in 1970, does not afford a valid and sufficient ground for failing to vote.
There is also a fundamental philosophical point at work here. A right to vote must, axiomatically, assume a non-vote. Engagement and abstention are choices, and while the latter may seem unwise and take you out of the running as a genuine “voice” – that term itself being less consequential in today’s mass industrialised and estranged societies – the assumption that you cannot do so by law creates the sense of a false choice.
Anyone, then, with an acquaintance with the taxonomy of rights should realise that the right to vote shades off into an obligation in this instance, transmuting into a matter of duty and obedience to the state. The trumpeted virtues of enfranchisement become a matter of command by the Australian Electoral Commission and the commonwealth. You are forced to vote for the lunatics on offer; but, you are also told that you can just as well do what is termed a “donkey vote”. This latter point shows a good deal of disingenuousness on the part of defenders of compulsory voting. You must be compelled to vote, but it does not mean you have to necessarily pick a choice on the ballot. A spoiled vote is still an indication of preference or lack of one. But why vote in the first place then? Because it is the right thing to do. And so the circular reasoning continues.
The inconsistencies here are rarely taken seriously in Australian debates (or non-debates) on the subject of compulsory voting. The duty masquerades ingloriously as a right. And lurking behind the high-minded principle is a more grounded political motivation. Historically, the Australian Labor Party encouraged compulsory voting to ensure that their voter base turned out in competitive numbers to those of their conservative opponents. As ever, more a case of survival than principle.
[textblock style=”7″]
Like what we do at The AIMN?
You’ll like it even more knowing that your donation will help us to keep up the good fight.
Chuck in a few bucks and see just how far it goes!
[/textblock]
I sent two months in China last year, living with and mixing with ordinary Chinese people (there is no such thing as an ‘ordinary’. Obese by the way – the country is extraordinarily large and the population so numerous and varied that on some excursions to the Great Wall and the Terracotta Army, although I was the only foreigner, there were people from the north and people from the south whose usual diet was as different from the others in the group as mine was.
I walked home in the early hours of the morning sometimes, through very run down neighbourhoods, at first apprehensive then completely comfortable, no sense of danger whatsoever. And I saw no police presence, although I knew it must be there. I would not walk around downtown Adelaide with such ease of mind. I would not walk around ANY city in the US, or the UK for that matter, after dark.
I found a people utterly at ease with itself, generally enjoying a standard of living – accommodation apart – as high as, if not higher than, mine. And buoyant.
I visited a city of 8 million where petrol driven vehicles were not allowed within 25 km of the centre. I saw parks that were exquisite, and historical buildings kept beautifully. No mention of politics and no obvious police presence. I was actually astonished. No mention of politics and no apparent interest in it. They remember what life was like under Chiang Kai Shek (and Mao – not really revered, to my surprise).
I wouldn’t want to live there, but I came home to a country that thinks it is superior but bloody-well isn’t.
Nobody is compelled to vote for anybody in Australia. We have compulsory attendance at the polling booth.
You can vote according to your preferences, write rude comments, vote like a donkey or leave it completely blank.
You are obliged by law to put your ballot papers in the boxes, but you are not compelled to vote.
Not to hard really.
Sharp insights…thank you Dr Kampmark
as always Binoy – much food for thought.
Thankfully early voting, without the need for an excuse, will maintain our compulsory voting and high voter turnout.
There is no excuse for a voter to be ignorant of the beliefs of candidates in the lower house through social media, direct contact or reputation. The informal and the donkey vote should be rare.
20 years ago the power of the donkey vote in my 3 member electorate was clearly visible. There was a statistical abnormality in that a considerable majority of the successful candidates had surnames from A to Mc
The candidate order on the ballot paper was alphabetical.
The knowalls from the south and our clp mouths were incensed that a candidate got the highest number of first preferences was not elected.
These ”anthony greenists were raving about the unfairness of the result. They were right in the conclusion of it being unfair but wrong in the reasoning. The problem was the order, if his name started with a different letter he would have received a very low number of ones
The candidate they wanted elected benefited from the donkey vote but when it came to preferences he never got to 50%
He was always in the 3rd in last 3 and the winner of the last two was the candidate with the earlier alphabetical surname. The southerners and local labor, clp and the greens analyst twits couldn’t see the connection with the donkey vote.
With my usual inability to explain lucidly or my disgraceful attitude to know it all southerners who treat territorians like women and mansplain. They left convinced this man should have been elected.
My point that the order on the ballot paper should be random so everyone has a chance at the donkey vote(with a beautiful side issue that ‘how to vote cards’ become useless) was unheard.
How to vote cards should be banned – as should all advertising and promotion on election day.